I have just finished a draft of this paper, which I will be presenting at the Socio-Legal Studies Association conference in York next week: or as much of it as can be done in twenty to thirty minutes. The full version is available on SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2236745
Thursday, 21 March 2013
Competition Law and UK retail banking
Friday, 15 March 2013
Cartel enforcement
Just before Christmas, Ali Nikpay, the OFT's senior director of the Cartels and Criminal Enforcement Group gave a very interesting talk to the Law Society Anti-trust section which can be found here: http://www.oft.gov.uk/shared_oft/speeches/2012/1112.pdf Although this is somewhat belated, I thought I would mention it because it is an excellent overview of the work of the OFT in relation to criminal enforcement, along with some thoughts about what the future might bring. The focus of this group is on criminal cartels, narrowly defined and criminal consumer law enforcement (a function which will presumably disappear following the creation of a Competition and Markets Authority). The whole speech is worth a read, particularly if you are interested in the OFT's current consultations on leniency and recently announced fining guidance.
The aim of the OFT is to develop a more proactive approach in this field, using the investigative powers that it has, including covert surveillance powers. There is also a warning that more director disqualification cases will be pursued.
As regards the criminal cartel offence, Ali Nikpay takes the view that the well-known enforcement problems are because of the requirement of dishonesty. He puts forward a strong case that reform was necessary and that the changes will not widen the offence unduly. On the former point, he argues that the requirement of dishonesty causes problems because "white-collar" crimes lack obvious indicators of dishonesty which means that likelihood of persuading a jury of the dishonesty of the conduct in a cartel case is far lower than many commentators assume and has been a major factor in the OFT's decision, in consultation with leading counsel, to close most of the criminal cartel cases they have launched so far. In addition, this has allowed defendants to create "dishonesty based defences", such as, "I was trying to protect jobs", "I was only following orders" etc. Despite these obstacles, he predicts one cartel case in the next year and another one to two in the next two to four years.
He makes the very god point that the criminal cartel offence is defined narrowly and does not catch, for example, vertical agreements and concerted practices. It is aimed at a small set of activities. He has confidence in the proposed publication exclusion because of its limited scope: only those customers directly affected by the offence need to be notified, only detail necessary to identify the existence of the conduct need be published and it only has to be published when the agreement is implemented. The example he gives is of a research and development joint venture and he emphasises that there would be no need to publish confidential information.
He is also confident that the new defences introduced into the offence will be effective. These are:
- the individual did not intend to conceal the arrangements from customers
- the individual did not intend that the arrangements would be concealed from the CMA
- before entering into the agreement, the individual took reasonable steps to ensure that the arrangements would be disclosed to a professional legal adviser for the purpose of obtaining advice about them before they were made or implemented (the 'professional advice defence').
Although the boat has sailed on this, I am still uncomfortable at the thought of sending people to prison, even if they have not acted dishonestly. I also think that the argument that dishonesty makes the offence very difficult to prove would be stronger if there were some actual examples of failing to prove this, although it's easier to write this than be responsible for a policy which would involve going against counsel's advice and bringing failed prosecutions (not a recipe for a successful career).
Public interest mergers
I have recently completed a draft, emphasis on draft, paper on public interest mergers which looks at, among other things, HBOS/Lloyds and News International/BSkyB. Having just worked out this new-fangled SSRN thing, you can find it here: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2233822 Any comments are very welcome.
Friday, 25 January 2013
Environmental concerns, non-economic objectives and washing machines
Having just marked a whole bunch of essays where students discussed the role, if any, of non-competition concerns in Article 101(3) TFEU analysis, which involved a discussion of the CECED decision by the Commission, I thought the following link was of interest: http://greedgreengrains.blogspot.co.uk/2012/12/do-consumers-benefit-from-energy.html It tells the story of what happened when the US Department of Energy increased standards for washing machines in 2007. The short version is that sales of less efficient washers reduced, although their prices increased and sales of more efficient washing machines increased significantly. The big point, however, is that the prices of the more efficient washing machines fell sharply around the time of the policy change. To quote: "… the price declines of the efficient washers was larger the price increases of the less efficient washers. And while overall quality of washers increased, average prices declined. Thus, not counting public and private benefits from energy saving, it seems pretty clear that consumers gained substantially from the policy change."
This is interesting because the CECED decision is often discussed as a case where the environmental objectives, energy efficiency, overruled or were at least of equal importance to the economic benefits to consumers, which were said to be less energy consumption and therefore cheaper bills. The analysis of the US case suggests that actually, and unexpectedly, there was no necessity to discuss environmental benefits – there were concrete economic benefits for consumers. It is politically useful to show competition law marching in step with environmental policy, but that is another issue.
My thanks to the Twitterfeed of Mark Thoma: @MarkThoma
Monday, 21 January 2013
The singing Professor
Congratulations to Amelia Fletcher, who has been appointed Professor of Competition Policy at the Centre for Competition Policy, University of East Anglia. The CCP's take is here: http://researchatccp.wordpress.com/2013/01/21/coverage-of-amelia-fletcher/
Professor Fletcher's side-line can be found here: http://www.myspace.com/tendertrap
Any other competition law and policy practitioners with interesting alternative activities?
St Gallen Competition Conference
St.Gallen International Competition Law Forum ICF - April 4th and 5th 2013
The 20th St.Gallen International Competition Law Forum ICF will be held on April 4th and 5th 2013. Once more, it will feature a thrilling selection of hot topics in current competition law issues and some of the most distinguished speakers in the field, including JoaquĆn Almunia (Vice-President of the EU Commission and Commissioner for Competition), Andreas Mundt (President of the German Competition Authority) and William Kovacic (Former Commissioner of the U.S. Federal Trade Commission ). Taking place in one of Switzerland's most beautiful cities, the St.Gallen ICF gives you the opportunity to meet, discuss and mingle with fellow competition lawyers and leading competition law experts from all over the world. Further information including a detailed programme are available on the conference website:http://www.sg-icf.ch/.
Topics: Current issues and developments in competition law
Programme: http://www.sg-icf.ch/programme/
Date: April 4th and 5th 2013
Location: St.Gallen, Switzerland
Registration: Registration is now open on our website (http://www.sg-icf.ch/conference-registration/)
Wednesday, 9 January 2013
Regulators and competition law enforcement
One of the slightly mysterious aspects of competition law enforcement in the UK is that, although a number of the independent regulators have concurrent competition powers alongside the OFT, they only use them rarely. The BIS consultation on the reform of competition law in the UK identified only two infringement decisions and there have not been any since the consultation paper. As one of the aims of the reforms has been to increase the number of enforcement decisions, the Enterprise and Regulatory Reform Bill included a number of changes to the legislation in order to encourage the regulators to use their competition law powers (contained in Clause 54 and Schedule 14).
Before Christmas, the government introduced a new clause into the Bill (http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/ld201213/ldhansrd/text/121218-gc0001.htm#12121867000429 at column GC 509). This clause would allow the Secretary of State, using a statutory instrument, to amend the Competition Act and/or the Enterprise Act to remove the concurrent competition powers that the regulators currently have (with the exception of Monitor). There are certain consultation requirements and the affirmative resolution procedure would have to be followed. The Minister, Lord Marland, explained that this was a reserve power, to be used if the new concurrency arrangements do not work or if there was "abuse of the system". This is a strong signal to the regulators that they will have to do better.
It is easy to state this, but more difficult to work out what it means. Presumably the regulators will not only have to bring more cases, but these cases will have to be successful, because bringing lots of unsuccessful cases would show that you are not using the system properly. How many cases could be expected in particular sectors of the economy? Some of the regulators, Ofwat, the CAA and the Northern Ireland regulator, might well struggle to generate all but the occasional case, for perfectly understandable reasons. The focus will presumably be on the performance of Ofcom, Ofgem and the Rail Regulator. Ofcom in particular, may well be under the spotlight, given that the CMA is to be chaired by Lord Currie and the chief executive designate, Alex Chisholm, has come from the Irish communications regulator. More decisions would mean more appearances in front of the CAT, something Ofcom, in particular, will not relish.
Who knows what the target will be? Where will the Minister obtain the information to assess the regulators' performance? Government departments are not in close contact with the relevant industries, except perhaps in rail, and the specialist consumer bodies have been closed down. If the nuclear option is exercised, there will be great pressure on the CMA to bring a case or cases soon after this has been done.
This is a policy based on assumption, for which there does not seem to be any evidence, that there are a number of competition problems in these industries, which the regulators need to solve through using their competition law powers. As Lord Berkeley spotted in the debate on the clause, this is a government impinging on the independence of the regulators through a strong suggestion that there are a series of correct decisions to be made.